Horowitz, D.L. (2015) ‘Irredentas and secessions: Adjacent phenomena, neglected connections’
12 October 2020
Horowitz, D.L. (2015) ‘Irredentas and secessions: Adjacent phenomena, neglected connections’, in K. Cordell and S. Wolff, eds. The Routledge Handbook of Ethnic Conflict, 2.ed., London, Routledge, 155-164.
- Secessions and irredentas have traditionally not been treated together, but they are deeply interconnected: the strength of one movement is related to the fact that the other may well rise – they are plausible alternatives to each other.
- Secession: attempt by an ethnic group claiming a homeland to withdraw with its territory from the authority of a larger state of which it is part (155).
- Irredentism: a movement by members of an ethnic group in one state to retrieve ethnically kindred people and their territory across borders.
- Both secession and irredentism contain various levels of intensity and various strategies (irredentism: incorporation into another state; creation of a new state from various irredentist groups).
- Secession: subtracting from an existing state; Irredentism: subtracting from one state and adding to another.
- There have been very few irredentas in postcolonial states, but many secessionist movements.
- Some international border disputes have no ethnic component; others contain compact ethnic groups that nevertheless do not dominate their region.
- When faced with a choice between the two, groups find secession the more satisfying choice. “Indeed, the potential for irredentism may increase the frequency and strength of secession, but not vice-versa” (157).
- Three issues that connect S and I:
- Convertibility of S and I:
- violence is convertible from one to the other;
- so is mutability of ethnic group claims and of trans-border affinities.
- State policies towards both also change over time: they tend to be inconstant towards I, which drives groups towards S.
- Ethnic affinity in one state may not extend to the irredentist group, also favoring S.
- Relative frequency of S and I:
- Irredentist action by the potential retrieving state is uncommon.
- Aid to S movements can be strategically terminated; aid to I movements cannot because they are underpinned by “an ideology of common fate” that does not lend itself to abrupt termination (160).
- In turn, irredentist groups find retrieval by another state undesirable because of their own personal interests as political leaders. S given them a better access to power, whilst I allows them to be challenged by leaders of retrieving state.
- Retrieving state itself may be heterogenous.
- Multiple secessions to build a new state (eg. Kurdistan) is almost impossible.
- In practice, even groups that have theoretically an I option do not really have it in practice and end up opting for S.
- “In short, all else being equal, the fewer the irredentas, the larger the number of secessionist movements” (161).
- Relative strength of S and I:
- Relative strength of a movement I affected by whether they chose S or I and whether the other is also available.
- States that are reluctant to engage in I claims may assist groups to achieve S (India / Bangladesh).
- Convertibility of S and I:
- When will an ethnoterritorial separatism movement take S or I courses? It’s a strategic choice based on calculations of rational interest.
- However, emotional factors cannot be discounted (eg. Ethnic affinity): secession movements continue to arise although secession almost always fails.